Rider, Thomas Duncan,
"The Tariff Policy of the Government of lndia
and its development Strategy, 1894-1924", Ph.D., Minnesota, 1971. – from
“summary and conclusions
“The most important requirement of tariff policy was
that it preserve the customs duties as a source of
revenue for the Government of India.
Tariff policy also must not impede economic development. Nor could it
jeopardize India's positive
balance of merchandise trade, which provided the Indian government with
sterling funds to meet its sterling obligations, supported the rupee exchange
rate, and provided the backing for India's silver currency…. It may be that at some time prior to 1894
attention to the well-being of British economic interests was an objective of
British policy in India;
between 1894 and 1924 it was a constraint on the formulation of tariff policy….
Budget deficits, caused … by the
depreciation in the rupee exchange, forced the Government of India in 1894
to impose a duty on imports. The initial exclusion of cotton yarn and cloth
from the import duty was necessitated by the ability of Manchester
export interests to prevent any tariff legislation in India that threatened the level of cotton
exports to India.
The exclusion of cottons, however, proved politically unpopular in India. As a
result, the final solution was to tax imports of cotton cloth and to
countervail that cotton duty with an excise on Indian yarn production. The
cotton duty and the countervailing excise, while popular with neither Bombay nor Manchester,
were tolerated by both. Though it had opposed concessions to Manchester, the Indian government accepted
the arrangement also because it was essential to the survival of the revenue
tariff. As a result of the stabilization of the rupee exchange in the late
1890s, the Government of India
avoided an increase in the general revenue duty, which would in turn have
jeopardized the concordat….. (T)he Indian revenue tariff was tolerable to
British export interests only so long as it did not affect the existing level
of trade… the India Office and therefore the Indian government was susceptible
to British pressure. Despite the imposition of a revenue duty, tariff policies
generally conformed to the British model and India's tariff policy could be
called a modified free trade policy. India
retained that modified free trade despite bilateralism in Europe and Imperial
preference within the British Empire. India generally
avoided bilateral agreements and with one exception did not discriminate among
her trading partners …. Nor did India grant preferences to Great Britain even though Britain's share of India's
import trade declined significantly after the adoption of free trade in India in the 1850s and even though the
self-governing colonies granted preferences to Britain. With India's balance of payments surplus helping to
finance Britain's deficits
with other countries, tariff reformers in Britain
could avoid the issue of India's
place in a general scheme of preferences. The price for India's acceptance
of a general scheme of Imperial preference, the right to protect selected
Indian industries, was a price which British export interests would be
unwilling to pay. The presence of British Liberals in office after 1905 halted
the extension of preferences to Britain
except for a single instance, the preferential treatment granted earlier by
Lord Curzon's government to British oil companies in
the exploitation of oil reserves in India
and Burma.
British
officials in India
were development minded. They believed the modified free trade policy to be
consistent with their development strategy. They encouraged the agricultural
export and transportation sectors, believing that development in those two
sectors would lead to the establishment of an industrial sector in India by
private enterprise. Indian agriculture, however, did not respond satisfactorily
to their promotional efforts. Nor had the expansion of India's
external trade and the construction of railways encouraged the development of
industries by Indians. Indian critics of
British economic policy convinced the Indian public that an agricultural
strategy could not achieve sufficient economic growth and that
industrialization by means of tariff protection was essential to economic
well-being. The use of tariff protection to correct India's
industrial insufficiency would, however, disturb the "Concordat of
1896," reduce the revenue yield of the Indian tariff, and require tariff
policy in India
to depart significantly from British tariff policy. Some industrial strategy
that excluded all-out tariff protection must be devised. The development of a
possible alternative industrial strategy, a program of state assistance and
entrepreneurship on the provincial level, was frustrated by Lord Morley's veto
in 1910.
… A diminution of the volume of India's foreign trade during the (First World) war and the likelihood that it would face
numerous trade restrictions after the war reinforced the view that foreign
trade would no longer prove an important growing point in the Indian economy.
Secondly, the acquisition by Japan
and America of markets held
by Europe prior to 1914 suggested that British exporters would face formidable
competition in the Indian market after the war and that the development of
import-replacement industries in India would not be possible without
tariff assistance. The continuation of a modified free trade policy was
unlikely to benefit either Indian manufactures or British exporters. Thirdly,
the temporary isolation of India
from European industrial competition and the additional demand generated by the
government's war effort stimulated the development of some young Indian
industries that would have difficulties once trade and demand conditions were
again normal. Finally, the dependence of India
upon Europe for many essential manufactured items encouraged British officials
to view greater industrial self-sufficiency as crucial to India's defense
posture. An industrial strategy that involved state industrial assistance and
enterprise, while preserving a low revenue tariff as a source of revenue, was
recommended by the Indian Industrial Commission in 1918. It was vetoed again,
this time by Indian politicians and by the Indian and European business
communities.
(With )The … working out of the
Fiscal Autonomy Convention between 1916 and 1922…. The
British cabinet also
accepted the Indian government's determination to grant tariff protection to
selected infant industries after the war. The interests surrounding
Indo-British trade were to be placated by the grant of preferences by India to
British goods. Autonomy in tariff matters became even more indispensable to
British officials in India as a result of three developments immediately after
the war: the constitutional reforms of 1919 which gave Indian politicians greater
influence over the decision-making process, the need to raise the tariff
revenue yields in 1921 and again in 1922, and the decision that India would
participate in bilateral negotiations with Britain and with the Empire
concerning preferential tariffs.
…
The Indian government ….
In 1919 India
indicated its willingness to grant preferences on a bilateral basis after a
British cabinet committee excluded the possibility of an Empire-wide scheme of
preferences but only if it received an offer from His Majesty's Government
sufficiently attractive to win over Indian public opinion. Indians were
demanding that India be
given the same degree of tariff autonomy as enjoyed by the self-governing
colonies and specifically that India
be allowed to protect her nascent industries.
While opposed to
high tariff protection, the Government of India was prepared to accept
"discriminating protection," that is, protection to selected infant
industries, and believed that it might do so without a radical revision of its
tariff which would disturb revenue yields and British
export interests. It was also willing to stand by its offer of selective
preferences to British imports in return for a satisfactory offer from Britain. A
commission to consider Indian tariff policy was forced upon the Indian
government, however, by Indian politicians, and the Indian Fiscal Commission,
while accepting tariff protection for Indian industries, proved cool to
Imperial preference. Fortunately the commission was moderate and recommended a retention of the revenue tariff. … The commission did not,
however, foresee the world depression in the 1930s and underestimated the
ability of Japanese importers to compete in the Indian market at the expense
of both Indian industries and British importers. Both the world depression and
Japanese imports were to upset the settlement that had been worked out in the
early 1920s.
The above
summary suggests the impact of Indian economic development on the formulation
of tariff policy. It does not attempt the reverse, that is, to assess the
impact of tariff policy on the process of economic development in India. The
latter task would raise considerable difficulties. It would not be easy to
isolate tariff policy as the variable factor in the performance of the economy
when there are many other factors that were more important in determining the
nature of Indian economic development than was tariff policy. Considering the
relative size of India's
foreign trade in relation to the total economy, the manipulation of tariff
rates up or down would have had a minimal impact on the performance of the
economy. It would even be difficult to determine the responsibility of tariff
policy for what many regard as India's
industrial insufficiency, given the much greater importance of agricultural
stagnation in India
as an explanation of that insufficiency.
Even if it
were shown that another tariff policy might have achieved a larger rate of
economic progress, measured in terms of net national product, it would have to
be shown that the faster rate of economic progress was appropriate to India's needs….
It is by no means certain that
maximizing the growth of the national product or even achieving the rate of economic
development experienced by Western Europe, the United
States, and Japan
would necessarily have been appropriate for India in the British period….
British economic policy, including
Indian tariff policy, has been judged inappropriate because it failed to
achieve an adequate growth rate, "adequate" being determined by the
European and American models. This is an arbitrary criterion. A more relevant critrion for evaluating tariff policy and the whole
development strategy of the British in India would be whether it generated
an appropriate economic structure, and how that structure affected Indian
society, culture, politics, etc. It may be that the rate of economic progress
in India
between the 1850s and the 1930s met adequately most societal needs even though
it fell short of the rate considered adequate by the Indian critics of British
policy or by many modern economists. It may be, on the other hand, that its
consideration of non-Indian interests in the formulation of economic policies
and its alien character made the British government in India unsuitable as an
instrument for achieving an appropriate economic structure even though British
administration did achieve some positive benefits for India.
It is also not
a sufficient indictment of British development strategy merely to point out
that it was constrained by political realities or to suggest that British
officials, in pursuing that strategy, made political compromises. Both are a
necessity for any bureaucracy at all vulnerable to political forces. Economic
plans that are not constrained by political realities and that can not bend to
political necessity are useless to a bureaucracy that must look to its base of
support. nationalist politicians were quarreling with
those political realities upon which economic policy rested. By doing so they
exerted a counterforce which allowed the Government of India to
concern itself less with British export interests. In other words they were
able to change political realities.
The
nationalist critique of economic policy performed another useful function. The
economic development of India
under the British involved social costs too often neglected by British
officials, and Indian politicians were correct to point them out. The development
of the agricultural export sector undoubtedly did make the peasantry more
vulnerable to draught and did require them to seek capital from money-lenders.
The development of transport probably did benefit imports and Indian industries
in transportation centers, particularly the port cities, more than it benefitted traditional industrial centers. wconomic development during the
British period did involve great costs to many-groups in India, and it
was appropriate for nationalists to ask whether the welfare gains exceeded
those costs.
Indian
Moderates generally recommended a more rapid rate of economic development as a
palliative for the social costs resulting from the development process.
Specifically they recommended all-out industrialization. It is doubtful that
industrialization would have reduced the social and cultural costs of economic
change; in fact Indians advocating all-out industrialization candidly admitted
that the social and economic costs of their program were high but assumed the
eventual welfare gains would exceed the costs involved. It is also not inappropriate
to question that assumption.
The unbalanced development strategy pursued by the
British in India may or may
not have been the optimal approach to economic development in India during
the British period. But given that strategy, the nature of the world economy,
the revenue needs of the Government of India,
and the existence of powerful export interests in Britain, the policy of modified
free trade was appropriate tariff policy for the Indian government in the
1890s. Economic and political realities changed considerably between 1894 and
1924, however, and by the end of the First World War, the policy of
discriminating protection was appropriate. The modified free trade policy and
then discriminating protection were both successful political settlements.
They were tolerated by the resident British commercial community and by the
British cabinet. Most Indian businessmen were not particularly protectionist
and seem to have been relatively satisfied with the modified free trade tariff
and then with discriminating protection, tariff policies they had had a hand in
shaping. The pattern of cooperation betwen
the major Indian business communities and British officials remained intact
into the late 1920s. Until then protectionist-minded politicians were not in a
position to force tariff protection on the bureaucracy. In the 1920s, however,
divisions had appeared among Indian politicians over tariff protection, and
other political demands had a higher priority.
The standard
imperial argument has exaggerated the influence of British economic interests
in Britain and in India over the
formulation of tariff policy and obscured the importance of other considerations.
Tariff policy is only one aspect of the total economic policy of the Indian
government, yet I would suspect that the considerations that determined other
economic policies are equally complex and the attempt to explain them in terms
of the imperial argument also an oversimplification. We shall be able to ask
more relevant questions about the nature of Indian economic development in the
British period, its adequacies and inadequacies, about the appropriateness of
British policy, about the impact of economic change on Indian society, and so
forth, if we avoid assuming the subservience of the Government of India to
British economic interests.
It may be that the British administration of India
handicapped or even prevented the Indian economy from responding successfully
to societal demands and to the opening up of India to the world economy. As of
yet, however, the verdict can not be pronounced. ”